The bestselling co-author of Why Nations Fail and the bestselling co-author of 13 Bankers deliver a bold reinterpretation of economics and history that will fundamentally change how you see the world.
Power and Progress is one of five titles shortlisted for the Lionel Gelber Prize, awarded annually by the University of Toronto Munk School of Global Affairs & Public Policy to the best English-language book on international affairs.
Learn moreNews
Dec 11, 2024
Media Coverage
Can Massive Technological Progress Hurt Workers? A Review of Power and Progress by Daron Acemoglu and Simon JohnsonNews
Nov 6, 2024
Media Coverage
Harvard Reads: Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and ProsperityPodcast
Oct 21, 2024
Interview
Tech, Power, and Progress: Nobel Laureate Simon Johnson on the Economics of ChangeNews
Oct 16, 2024
Interview
Who Really Benefits from Tech Innovation?Podcast
Oct 4, 2024
Interview
Behavioral Scientist: A Techno-Visions Conversation with Simon JohnsonNews
Sep 20, 2024
Event Recording
Daron Acemoglu delivers 2024 Stone Lecture in Economic InequalityNews
Sep 9, 2024
Interview
Hoshimov’s Economics: Daron Acemoglu – Our Struggle Over Technology and ProsperityNews
Aug 29, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress featured on New America Labor Day 2024 reading listNews
Aug 1, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress named to Science|Business’s summer reads of 2024News
Jul 23, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress named to Wharton Faculty Summer Reading ListPodcast
Jul 22, 2024
Interview
Sean Carroll’s Mindscape Podcast: Daron Acemoglu on Technology, Inequality, and PowerNews
Jul 11, 2024
Interview
HBS Institute for Business in Global Society: Big Tech Poses Risks as AI Reshapes SocietyNews
Jun 24, 2024
Media Coverage
Berkeley Law Library selects Power and Progress for 2024 Summer Reading ListNews
Jun 4, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress named to AI and Democracy Summer Reading ListNews
May 6, 2024
Media Coverage
Latercera: La columna de Javier Salinas: “El camino que decidamos tomar”News
Apr 26, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress featured in O’Reilly Next Economy NewsletterPodcast
Apr 9, 2024
Interview
OECD Berlin Centre: Tête-à-Tête with Daron AcemoğluNews
Apr 4, 2024
Event Recording
Daron Acemoglu presents Power and Progress at the University of ChicagoPodcast
Mar 5, 2024
Interview
Tech on the Hill Podcast: How Will AI Change Labor Markets and What Can We Do About It?News
Feb 28, 2024
Event Recording
United States Senate Committee on Armed Services HearingNews
Feb 13, 2024
Event Recording
Daron Acemoglu at the launch of Poder y progreso: La lucha milenaria por la tecnología y la prosperidadNews
Feb 8, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress shortlisted for the 2024 Lionel Gelber PrizePodcast
Feb 2, 2024
Interview
People I (Mostly) Admire: Daron Acemoglu on Economics, Politics, and PowerNews
Jan 31, 2024
Event Recording
UNU WIDER Annual Lecture 26: Technology and inequality in the past and futureNews
Jan 23, 2024
Interview
PublicAffairs: Can We Build an Alternative Economy? A Conversation with Nick Romeo and Simon JohnsonPodcast
Jan 21, 2024
Interview
Simon Johnson on Econofact Chats: The Social Bias of Technological Change (Re-broadcast)News
Jan 10, 2024
Media Coverage
Power and Progress featured in Behavioral Scientist’s Notable Books of 2023 listNews
Jan 2, 2024
Media Coverage
Forbes: Power and Progress named one of Top 10 Tech Books Of 2023News
Dec 29, 2023
Interview
Le Temps: French language interview with Simon JohnsonNews
Dec 29, 2023
Media Coverage
Bloomberg: Walter Isaacson and Michael Lewis Didn’t Write the Only Business Books in 2023News
Dec 26, 2023
Media Coverage
ProMarket: The Best Political Economy Books from 2023News
Dec 22, 2023
Interview
PBS NewsHour: The historic struggle between workers and the technology that could put them out of a jobNews
Dec 20, 2023
Media Coverage
IMF: Economists Offer Fresh Takes on Inflation, Inequality, TechnologyNews
Dec 20, 2023
Event Recording
Generative AI Ethics and Society: Simon JohnsonNews
Dec 18, 2023
Media Coverage
Ideas Made to Matter: Generative AI research from MIT SloanNews
Dec 6, 2023
Media Coverage
Power and Progress named to Prospect Magazine Books of the year 2023: Ideas listNews
Dec 1, 2023
Event Recording
The Financial Issues Forum: Daron Acemoglu on Power and ProgressOp-Ed
Nov 30, 2023
Op-Ed
IMF Finance & Development: Rebalancing AINews
Nov 28, 2023
Media Coverage
CEO Magazine names Power and Progress one of 13 best business books of 2023News
Nov 27, 2023
Event Recording
Daron Acemoglu: Is It Better for a Machine to Be Intelligent? Or Useful?News
Nov 27, 2023
Media Coverage
Power and Progress on MIT Sloan’s 2023 reading listNews
Nov 27, 2023
Media Coverage
Power and Progress named on Project Syndicate Holiday 2023 Reading ListNews
Nov 14, 2023
Media Coverage
Financial Times names Power and Progress one of six best technology books of 2023News
Nov 14, 2023
Event Recording
Webinar: Lanzamiento del libro Power and Progress with Simon JohnsonNews
Nov 13, 2023
Event Recording
CDT Digital Leadership Series: Achieving Shared Prosperity in The Age Of AINews
Nov 9, 2023
Event Recording
World Inequality Lab Webinar on Power and ProgressPodcast
Oct 26, 2023
Media Coverage
Pablo Torre Finds Out: What You Should Know About Artificial Intelligence (and Why Centaurs Are Our Future)Op-Ed
Oct 25, 2023
SSIR: Choosing AI’s Impact on the Future of WorkPodcast
Oct 25, 2023
Humanity’s Enduring Quest for Power and Prosperity – Daron AcemogluPodcast
Oct 23, 2023
Peering Into A.I.’s Black Box, Who’s the Real Techno-Optimist? and Reading Ancient Scrolls with A.I.News
Oct 17, 2023
Daron Acemoglu: “The impact of artificial intelligence will be a mix of the printing press, the steam engine and the atomic bomb”News
Oct 17, 2023
La Sexta Features Poder y Progreso as Book of the DayNews
Sep 27, 2023
Daron Acemoglu Receives A.SK Social Science AwardNews
Sep 25, 2023
Dagens Arena: The market cannot create growth and prosperity on its ownNews
Sep 25, 2023
Book review: US economists ponder ways to make tech serve the peopleNews
Sep 25, 2023
The Parliament: Is technology our friend or our foe? ‘Power and Progress’ dives inNews
Sep 21, 2023
MIT scholars awarded seed grants to probe the social implications of generative AINews
Sep 21, 2023
New York Times: Tech Fears are Showing Up on Picket LinesNews
Sep 20, 2023
BBC News Brasil: Lula needs to improve the lives of the middle class to strengthen democracy, says AcemogluNews
Sep 18, 2023
Business Insider:The AI heretic: How a leading economist learned to start worrying and fear artificial intelligencePodcast
Sep 13, 2023
Keen On: How to direct the power of digital technology into economic and political progressNews
Sep 12, 2023
MIT Sloan Management Review: Why the Power of Technology Rarely Goes to the PeoplePodcast
Sep 12, 2023
Converging Dialogues: Power and Progress: A Dialogue with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Sep 11, 2023
Sinica Podcast: The case for the U.S.-China Science and Technology AgreementNews
Sep 11, 2023
The Hundred Interview: Daron Acemoglu on Technology and ProsperityNews
Sep 11, 2023
Agenda Publica: The proto-strike against artificial intelligenceNews
Sep 8, 2023
Psychology Today: Big Tech and Its Discontents: Does technology still have what it takes to make life better?News
Sep 8, 2023
Literary Hub: Here’s the longlist for the 2023 Baillie Gifford Prize for NonfictionNews
Sep 8, 2023
Publishing Perspectives: The £50,000 Baillie Gifford Prize Names Its LonglistNews
Sep 8, 2023
The Guardian: Slavery, revolution and war: Baillie Gifford prize longlist highlights historyNews
Sep 8, 2023
The Times UK: Baillie Gifford Prize 2023: are these the best non-fiction books of the year?News
Sep 8, 2023
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Book ReviewNews
Sep 7, 2023
Chosun: Why pour cold water on the AI fantasy? Because there is no such thing as ‘good technology’News
Sep 7, 2023
WBUR: Summer reading picks from Traci Thomas and Scott TongNews
Aug 28, 2023
El Comercio: Poder y progreso: la mano visible de la IANews
Aug 28, 2023
Washington Post: CEOs Must Soldier On Even as AI Anxieties LoomNews
Aug 27, 2023
Lowy Institute on Embracing DigitalizationNews
Aug 27, 2023
The Conversation: How the work of Adam Smith could help solve the UK skills gapNews
Aug 27, 2023
Chicago Booth Review: “If Big Tech Is a Problem, What’s the Solution?”Podcast
Aug 27, 2023
Deadline‘s “Strike Talk” Podcast with Billy RayNews
Aug 27, 2023
Reuters: “Will AI be an economic blessing or curse? History offers clues”News
Aug 25, 2023
Project Syndicate: The Political Economy of TechnologyNews
Aug 25, 2023
Der Spiegel“Our future will be very dystopian” – Interview with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Aug 24, 2023
Metis Strategy Podcast with Daron AcemogluNews
Aug 18, 2023
Financial Times: Business Book of the Year 2023 — the longlistNews
Aug 18, 2023
The Economist: The battle between American workers and technology heats upNews
Aug 2, 2023
Professor John Tasioulas endorses Power and Progress in interview with The Greek HeraldOp-Ed
Aug 2, 2023
Project Syndicate: The Hollywood Writers’ AI Fight Is Everyone’s FightPodcast
Aug 2, 2023
BCG’s Thinkers & Ideas with Simon JohnsonPodcast
Jul 27, 2023
Daron Acemoglu appears on Forward with Andrew YangPodcast
Jul 27, 2023
Existential Hope podcast with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Jul 19, 2023
“Podcast Das EconomistAs” interview with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Jul 19, 2023
Kim Jiyoon’s Knowledge Play with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Jul 17, 2023
Society of Professional Economists Interview with Simon JohnsonPodcast
Jul 11, 2023
“Behind the Markets” Podcast with Simon JohnsonNews
Jul 11, 2023
Vox: What 1,000 years of history can teach us about making the economy of AI work for everyoneNews
Jul 11, 2023
Inside Higher Ed: Technology, Higher Education, and ‘Power and Progress’News
Jul 5, 2023
Notable Nonfiction of Early Summer 2023 by Five BooksNews
Jun 30, 2023
WBUR: “How technology should lead to shared economic growth”Op-Ed
Jun 29, 2023
Project Syndicate: Would AI-Enabled Communism Work?Podcast
Jun 29, 2023
ROCKING OUR PRIORS interview with Alice EvansPodcast
Jun 23, 2023
Freakonomics Radio Features Power and ProgressNews
Jun 22, 2023
Martin Wolf’s list of “Best summer books of 2023: Economics”News
Jun 22, 2023
Financial Times: Best summer books of 2023 on technologyNews
Jun 14, 2023
E&T Interviews Simon Johnson on Power and ProgressOp-Ed
Jun 12, 2023
Microsoft Unlocked: What should we want from machines?News
Jun 12, 2023
The New York Times: The A.I. Revolution Will Change Work. Nobody Agrees How.News
Jun 12, 2023
Behavioral Scientist’s Summer Book List 2023News
Jun 12, 2023
Financial Times: The best new books on economicsOp-Ed
Jun 12, 2023
Project Syndicate: Will Democracies Stand Up to Big Brother?Op-Ed
Jun 9, 2023
Op-Ed
New York Times: Big Tech Is Bad. Big A.I. Will Be Worse.Podcast
Jun 6, 2023
Faster, Please! — The Podcast #28: Simon Johnson on Technology and ProsperityPodcast
Jun 6, 2023
AI is Overhyped, Will Only Worsen Inequality: Simon JohnsonPodcast
Jun 2, 2023
VoxTalks Economics: Daron Acemoglu Interviewed on Power and ProgressNews
Jun 1, 2023
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond: Econ Focus Second QuarterPodcast
Jun 1, 2023
Good Morning Scotland: Interview with Daron AcemogluPodcast
Jun 1, 2023
Stephanomics: The Key to Making AI a Benefit, Not a HazardPodcast
Jun 1, 2023
BBC Radio 3 Interview with Daron AcemogluPodcast
May 30, 2023
Daron Acemoglu on Technology and the Struggle for Shared ProsperityNews
May 26, 2023
What neo-Luddites get right — and wrong — about Big TechNews
May 24, 2023
New York Times: A.I. May Help Design Your Favorite Video Game CharacterNews
May 24, 2023
New York Times: The Optimist’s Guide to Artificial Intelligence and WorkNews
May 24, 2023
Simon Johnson on why the current banking crisis is unlike the 2008 meltdownNews
May 24, 2023
Technology on trial: Do AI advances mean humanity is now in its final days?Podcast
May 19, 2023
Deadline’s Strike Talk Podcast: MIT’s Simon Johnson On A.I.News
May 19, 2023
Economist Daron Acemoglu: ‘When mistakes involve powerful technologies, you’re going to have trouble’Podcast
May 18, 2023
Capitalisn’t: Is Technological Progress Good For Everyone?News
May 17, 2023
Why use of AI is a major sticking point in the ongoing writers’ strikePodcast
May 17, 2023
When Stephen Kinsella met Simon Johnson: Power, progress, and the Irish economyPodcast
May 17, 2023
Have a Nice Future podcast: How Humanity Can Avoid an AI TakeoverPodcast
May 17, 2023
Conversations with Tyler podcast: Simon Johnson on Banking, Technology, and Prosperity (Ep. 179)Podcast
May 17, 2023
Simon Johnson on Economics & Beyond podcast with Rob JohnsonNews
May 17, 2023
Book excerpt: It’s time to rechart the course of technology. Here are 4 ways to startPodcast
May 10, 2023
Bankers Behaving Badly: SVB, the Fed & FDIC Reports, and the Path ForwardNews
May 8, 2023
Equitable Growth in Conversation with Daron AcemogluPodcast
May 7, 2023
A Chat with Daron Acemoglu on Power and ProgressNews
May 7, 2023
Power and Progress review – why the tech-equals-progress narrative must be challengedPodcast
May 5, 2023
New Books Network discussion with Simon JohnsonOp-Ed
May 5, 2023
Opinion: The writers’ strike is partly about AI. They’re right to worryPodcast
May 4, 2023
Private Equity Discussion with Simon JohnsonNews
May 2, 2023
Is AI coming for your job? How it could impact the job market and the 4 positions that are safe betsNews
May 1, 2023
Ezra Klein Answers Listener Questions on A.I.News
May 1, 2023
ChatGPT is about to revolutionize the economy. We need to decide what that looks like.News
May 1, 2023
The Next Big Idea Club’s May 2023 Must-Read BooksLearn more about past events for Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and Prosperity and watch the recordings.
The Co-Directors of the MIT Shaping the Future of Work Initiative, Daron Acemoglu, David Autor, and Simon Johnson, have released a plan to choose the best path for AI development, answering the question: “Can We Have Pro-Worker AI?” Read the policy memo.
From the summary, here are the five most important federal policies to pursue at this time:
Research that underlies this policy memo has been supported by many different funding organizations over the last decade. Acemoglu gratefully acknowledges financial support for related projects from Accenture, the Air Force Office of Scientific Research, the Army Research Office, the Bradley Foundation, the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, the Department of Economics at MIT, Google, the Hewlett Foundation, IBM, Microsoft, the National Science Foundation, Schmidt Sciences, the Sloan Foundation, and the Toulouse Network on Information Technology. Autor gratefully acknowledges financial support for related projects from Google, the Hewlett Foundation, the NOMIS Foundation, and the Washington Center for Equitable Growth. Johnson gratefully acknowledges support from the Sloan School, MIT.
Prologue
What Is Progress?
Every day, we hear from executives, journalists, politicians, and even some of our colleagues at MIT that we are heading relentlessly toward a better world, thanks to unprecedented advances in technology. Here is your new phone. There goes the latest electric car. Welcome to the next generation of social media. And soon, perhaps, scientific advances could solve cancer, global warming, and even poverty.
Of course, problems remain, including inequality, pollution, and extremism around the globe. But these are the birth pains of a better world. In any case, we are told, the forces of technology are inexorable. We couldn’t stop them if we wanted to, and it would be highly inadvisable to try. It is better to change ourselves—for example, by investing in skills that will be valued in the future. If there are continuing problems, talented entrepreneurs and scientists will invent solutions—more-capable robots, human-level artificial intelligence, and whatever other breakthroughs are required. People understand that not everything promised by Bill Gates, Elon Musk, or even Steve Jobs will likely come to pass. But, as a world, we have become infused by their techno-optimism. Everyone everywhere should innovate as much as they can, figure out what works, and iron out the rough edges later.
WE HAVE BEEN here before, many times. One vivid example began in 1791, when Jeremy Bentham proposed the panopticon, a prison design. In a circular building and with the right lighting, Bentham argued, centrally positioned guards could create the impression of watching everyone all the time, without themselves being observed supposedly a very efficient (low-cost) way of ensuring good behavior.
The idea at first found some traction with the British government, but sufficient funding was not forthcoming, and the original version was never built. Nevertheless, the panopticon captured the modern imagination. For the French philosopher Michel Foucault, it is a symbol of oppressive surveillance at the heart of industrial societies. In George Orwell’s 1984, it operates as the omnipresent means of social control. In the Marvel movie Guardians of the Galaxy, it proves to be a flawed design that facilitates an ingenious prison breakout.
Before the panopticon was proposed as a prison, it was a factory. The idea originated with Samuel Bentham, Jeremy’s brother and an expert naval engineer then working for Prince Grigory Potemkin in Russia. Samuel’s idea was to enable a few supervisors to watch over as many workers as possible. Jeremy’s contribution was to extend that principle to many kinds of organizations. As he explained to a friend, “You will be surprised when you come to see the efficacy which this simple and seemingly obvious contrivance promises to be to the business of schools, manufactories, Prisons, and even Hospitals. . . .”
The panopticon’s appeal is easy to understand—if you are in charge—and was not missed by contemporaries. Better surveillance would lead to more compliant behavior, and it was easy to imagine how this could be in the broader interest of society. Jeremy Bentham was a philanthropist, animated by schemes to improve social efficiency and help everyone to greater happiness, at least as he saw it. Bentham is credited today as the founder of the philosophy of utilitarianism, which means maximizing the combined welfare of all people in society. If some people could be squeezed a little in return for a few people gaining a great deal, that was an improvement worth considering.
The panopticon was not just about efficiency or the common good, however. Surveillance in factories implied inducing workers to labor harder, and without the need to pay them higher wages to motivate greater effort.
The factory system spread rapidly in the second half of the eighteenth century across Britain. Even though they did not rush to install panopticons, many employers organized work in line with Bentham’s general approach. Textile manufacturers took over activities previously performed by skilled weavers and divided them up more finely, with key elements now done by new machines. Factory owners employed unskilled workers, including women and small children, to perform simple repetitive tasks, such as pulling a handle, for as many as fourteen hours per day.They also supervised this labor force closely, lest anyone slow down production. And they paid low wages.
Workers complained about conditions and the backbreaking effort. Most egregious to many were the rules they had to follow in factories. One weaver put it this way in 1834: “No man would like to work in a power-loom, they do not like it, there is such a clattering and noise it would almost make some men mad; and next, he would have to be subject to a discipline that a hand-loom weaver can never submit to.”
New machinery turned workers into mere cogs. As another weaver testified before a parliamentary committee in April 1835, “I am determined for my part, that if they will invent machines to supersede manual labour, they must find iron boys to mind them.”
To Jeremy Bentham, it was self-evident that technology improvements enabled better-functioning schools, factories, prisons, and hospitals, and this was beneficial for everyone. With his flowery language, formal dress, and funny hat, Bentham would cut an odd figure in modern Silicon Valley, but his thinking is remarkably fashionable. New technologies, according to this view of the world, expand human capabilities and, when applied throughout the economy, greatly increase efficiency and productivity. Then, the logic goes, society will sooner or later find a way of sharing these gains, generating benefits for pretty much everybody.
Adam Smith, the eighteenth-century founding father of modern economics, could also join the board of a venture capital fund or write for Forbes. In his view, better machines would lead to higher wages, almost automatically:
In consequence of better machinery, of greater dexterity, and of a more proper division and distribution of work, all of which are the natural effects of improvement, a much smaller quantity of labour becomes requisite for executing any particular piece of work, and though, in consequence of the flourishing circumstances of the society, the real price of labour should rise very considerably. . . .
In any case, resistance is futile. Edmund Burke, contemporary of Bentham and Smith, referred to the laws of commerce as “the laws of nature, and consequently the laws of God.”
How can you resist the laws of God? How can you resist the unstoppable march of technology? And anyway, why resist these advances?
ALL OF THIS optimism notwithstanding, the last thousand years of history are filled with instances of new inventions that brought nothing like shared prosperity:
• A whole series of technological improvements in medieval and early modern agriculture, including better plows, smarter crop rotation, more use of horses, and much improved mills, created almost no benefits for peasants, who constituted close to 90 percent of the population.
• Advances in European ship design from the late Middle Ages enabled transoceanic trade and created massive fortunes for some Europeans. But the same kinds of ships also transported millions of enslaved people from Africa to the New World and made it possible to build systems of oppression that lasted for generations and created awful legacies persisting today.
• Textile factories of the early British industrial revolution generated great wealth for a few but did not raise worker incomes for almost a hundred years. On the contrary, as the textile workers themselves keenly understood, work hours lengthened and conditions were horrible, both in the factory and in crowded cities.
• The cotton gin was a revolutionary innovation, greatly raising the productivity of cotton cultivation and turning the United States into the largest cotton exporter in the world. The same invention intensified the savagery of slavery as cotton plantations expanded across the American South.
• At the end of the nineteenth century, German chemist Fritz Haber developed artificial fertilizers that boosted agricultural yields. Subsequently, Haber and other scientists used the same ideas to design chemical weapons that killed and maimed hundreds of thousands on World War I battlefields.
• As we discuss in the second half of this book, spectacular advances in computers have enriched a small group of entrepreneurs and business tycoons over the last several decades, whereas most Americans without a college education have been left behind, and many have even seen their real incomes decline.
Some readers may object at this point: Did we not in the end hugely benefit from industrialization? Aren’t we more prosperous than earlier generations, who toiled for a pittance and often died hungry, thanks to improvements in how we produce goods and services?
Yes, we are greatly better off than our ancestors. Even the poor in Western societies enjoy much higher living standards today than three centuries ago, and we live much healthier, longer lives, with comforts that those alive a few hundred years ago could not have even imagined. And, of course, scientific and technological progress is a vital part of that story and will have to be the bedrock of any future process of shared gains. But the broad-based prosperity of the past was not the result of any automatic, guaranteed gains of technological progress. Rather, shared prosperity emerged because, and only when, the direction of technological advances and society’s approach to dividing the gains were pushed away from arrangements that primarily served a narrow elite. We are beneficiaries of progress, mainly because our predecessors made that progress work for more people. As the eighteenth-century writer and radical John Thelwall recognized, when workers congregated in factories and cities, it became easier for them to rally around common interests and make demands for more equitable participation in the gains from economic growth:
The fact is, that monopoly, and the hideous accumulation of capital in a few hands, like all diseases not absolutely mortal, carry, in their own enormity, the seeds of cure. Man is, by his very nature, social and communicative—proud to display the little knowledge he possesses, and eager, as opportunity presents, to encrease his store. Whatever presses men together, therefore, though it may generate some vices, is favourable to the diffusion of knowledge, and ultimately promotive of human liberty. Hence every large workshop and manufactory is a sort of political society, which no act of parliament can silence, and no magistrate disperse.
Electoral competition, the rise of trade unions, and legislation to protect workers’ rights changed how production was organized and wages were set in nineteenth-century Britain. Combined with the arrival of a new wave of innovation from the United States, they also forged a new direction of technology—focused on increasing worker productivity rather than just substituting machinery for the tasks they used to perform or inventing new ways of monitoring them. Over the next century, this technology spread throughout Western Europe and then the world. Most people around the globe today are better off than our ancestors because citizens and workers in early industrial societies organized, challenged elite-dominated choices about technology and work conditions, and forced ways of sharing the gains from technical improvements more equitably.
Today we need to do the same again.
The good news is that incredible tools are available to us, including magnetic resonance imaging (MRI), mRNA vaccines, industrial robots, the internet, tremendous computational power, and massive amounts of data on things we could not measure before. We can use these innovations to solve real problems—but only if these awesome capabilities are focused on helping people. This is not the direction in which we are currently heading, however.
Despite what history teaches us, the predominant narrative today has shifted back toward something remarkably close to what was prevalent in Britain 250 years ago. We are living in an age that is even more blindly optimistic and more elitist about technology than the times of Jeremy Bentham, Adam Smith, and Edmund Burke. As we document in Chapter 1, people making the big decisions are once again deaf to the suffering created in the name of progress.
We wrote this book to show that progress is never automatic. Today’s “progress” is again enriching a small group of entrepreneurs and investors, whereas most people are disempowered and benefit little.
A new, more inclusive vision of technology can emerge only if the basis of social power changes. This requires, as in the nineteenth century, the rise of counterarguments and organizations that can stand up to the conventional wisdom. Confronting the prevailing vision and wresting the direction of technology away from the control of a narrow elite may even be more difficult today than it was in nineteenth-century Britain and America. But it is no less essential.
The MIT Shaping the Future of Work Initiative has calculated preliminary estimates of the workforce effects from automation driven by generative AI platforms like ChatGPT. Read the policy memo. Here is an excerpt:
Roughly 1.6–3.2 million workers could lose their jobs over the next 20+ years, around 1–2% of total US employment via May 2022 OEWS. These are gross job losses, we expect many of these people will find new employment. Based on the observed effects from other, similar employment shifts in US history, this may coincide with wage declines of ~33–47% for the demographic groups which are engaged in occupations most-exposed to generative AI, relative to others who are less exposed to this form of automation.
Initiative Co-Director Daron Acemoglu has a new NBER working paper, cowritten with Todd Lensman, proposing a framework for “Regulating Transformative Technologies.” Here is a summary:
Transformative technologies like generative AI promise to accelerate productivity growth across many sectors, but they also present new risks of potential misuse. We develop a multi-sector technology adoption model to study the optimal regulation of transformative technologies when society can learn about these risks over time. Socially optimal adoption is gradual and convex. If social damages are proportional to the productivity gains from the new technology, a higher growth rate leads to slower optimal adoption. Equilibrium adoption is inefficient when firms do not internalize all social damages. Sector-independent regulation is helpful but generally not sufficient to restore optimality.
View the Power and Progress slide deck that Daron Acemoglu and Simon Johnson have used to present their findings to a range of audiences.
Hear the official excerpt from HachetteAudio on SoundCloud, as read by Malcolm Hillgartner.
Listen to the full audiobook on your platform of choice.
“The antidemocratic turn of technology, and how we turn it back.”
Available via ChangeThis from Porchlight Books.
“It’s time to rechart the course of technology. Here are 4 ways to start.”
Available via Ideas Made to Matter from MIT Sloan.
Find answers to frequently asked questions and a list of key definitions from the book, based on over 100 presentations and talks given around the world since Power and Progress was published in May 2023.
The bestselling co-author of Why Nations Fail and the bestselling co-author of 13 Bankers deliver a bold reinterpretation of economics and history that will fundamentally change how you see the world